(A synergistic relationship) Two individuals are involved in a synergistic relationship. If both…
(If you know calculus, you can reach the same conclusion by setting the derivative of player i’s payoff with respect to ai equal to zero.) The best response functions are shown in Figure 38.1. Player 1’s actions are plotted on the horizontal axis and player 2’s actions are plotted on the vertical axis. Player 1’s best response function associates an action for player 1 with every action for player 2. Thus to interpret the function b1 in the diagram, take a point a2 on the vertical axis, and go across to the line labeled b1 (the steeper of the two lines), then read down to the horizontal axis. The point on the horizontal axis that you reach is b1(a2), the best action for player 1 when player 2 chooses a2. Player 2’s best response function, on the other hand, associates an action for player 2 with every action of player 1. Thus to interpret this function, take a point a1 on the horizontal axis, and go up to b2, then across to the vertical axis. The point on the vertical axis that you reach is b2(a1), the best action for player 2 when player 1 chooses a1
At a point (a1, a2) where the best response functions intersect in the figure, we have a1 = b1(a2), because (a1, a2) is on the graph of b1, player 1’s best response function, and a2 = b2(a1), because (a1, a2) is on the graph of b2, player 1’s best response function. Thus any such point (a1, a2) is a Nash equilibrium. In this game the best response functions intersect at a single point, so there is one Nash equilibrium. In general, they may intersect more than once; every point at which they intersect is a Nash equilibrium. To find the point of intersection of the best response functions precisely, we can solve the two equations:
Substituting the second equation in the first, we get a1 = ½(c + ½ (c + a1)) = 3/4 c + ¼ a1, so that a1 = c. Substituting this value of a1 into the second equation, we get a2 = c. We conclude that the game has a unique Nash equilibrium (a1, a2) = (c, c). (To reach this conclusion, it suffices to solve the two equations; we do not have to draw Figure 38.1. However, the diagram shows us at once that the game has a unique equilibrium, in which both players’ actions exceed ½ c, facts that serve to check the results of our algebra.) In the game in this example, each player has a unique best response to every action of the other player, so that the best response functions are lines. If a player has many best responses to some of the other players’ actions, then her best response function is “thick” at some points; several examples in the next chapter have this property (see, for example, Figure 64.1). Example 37.1 is special also because the game has a unique Nash equilibrium—the best response functions cross once. As we have seen, some games have more than one equilibrium, and others have no equilibrium. A pair of best response functions that illustrates some of the possibilities is shown in Figure 39.1. In this figure the shaded area of player 1’s best re
Looking for a Similar Assignment? Let us take care of your accounting classwork while you enjoy your free time! All papers are written from scratch and are 100% Original. Try us today! Active Discount Code FREE15
